-
Notifications
You must be signed in to change notification settings - Fork 0
/
Paper.Rnw
517 lines (373 loc) · 68.6 KB
/
Paper.Rnw
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101
102
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
117
118
119
120
121
122
123
124
125
126
127
128
129
130
131
132
133
134
135
136
137
138
139
140
141
142
143
144
145
146
147
148
149
150
151
152
153
154
155
156
157
158
159
160
161
162
163
164
165
166
167
168
169
170
171
172
173
174
175
176
177
178
179
180
181
182
183
184
185
186
187
188
189
190
191
192
193
194
195
196
197
198
199
200
201
202
203
204
205
206
207
208
209
210
211
212
213
214
215
216
217
218
219
220
221
222
223
224
225
226
227
228
229
230
231
232
233
234
235
236
237
238
239
240
241
242
243
244
245
246
247
248
249
250
251
252
253
254
255
256
257
258
259
260
261
262
263
264
265
266
267
268
269
270
271
272
273
274
275
276
277
278
279
280
281
282
283
284
285
286
287
288
289
290
291
292
293
294
295
296
297
298
299
300
301
302
303
304
305
306
307
308
309
310
311
312
313
314
315
316
317
318
319
320
321
322
323
324
325
326
327
328
329
330
331
332
333
334
335
336
337
338
339
340
341
342
343
344
345
346
347
348
349
350
351
352
353
354
355
356
357
358
359
360
361
362
363
364
365
366
367
368
369
370
371
372
373
374
375
376
377
378
379
380
381
382
383
384
385
386
387
388
389
390
391
392
393
394
395
396
397
398
399
400
401
402
403
404
405
406
407
408
409
410
411
412
413
414
415
416
417
418
419
420
421
422
423
424
425
426
427
428
429
430
431
432
433
434
435
436
437
438
439
440
441
442
443
444
445
446
447
448
449
450
451
452
453
454
455
456
457
458
459
460
461
462
463
464
465
466
467
468
469
470
471
472
473
474
475
476
477
478
479
480
481
482
483
484
485
486
487
488
489
490
491
492
493
494
495
496
497
498
499
500
501
502
503
504
505
506
507
508
509
510
511
512
513
514
515
516
517
% % document type % %
\documentclass{cup_PSRM}
% % preamble % %
\usepackage{harvard} % bibliography
\usepackage{amsmath} % centers and provides equation numbers for align env
\usepackage{amssymb} % allows use of normal N symbol
\usepackage{bm} % bold greek letters
\usepackage{graphicx} % allows graphics floats
\usepackage{grffile} % allows more image file names
\usepackage{subcaption} % allows subfigures in floats
\newcommand{\subfloat}[2][need a sub-caption]{\subcaptionbox{#1}{#2}} % % knitr subfigures
\usepackage[hidelinks]{hyperref} % allows URLs and in-document hyperlinking
\usepackage{setspace} % allows line spacing
\usepackage{rotating} % allow sideways table environment
\usepackage{moreverb} % allows use of verbatimtab
\renewcommand\verbatimtabsize{4\relax} % sets verbatimtab indent to half of default, looks better
%\usepackage{parskip} % don't indent new paragraphs
\usepackage{dcolumn} % align table zeros
\newtheorem{hyp}{Hypothesis} % hypothesis formatting
% For \email{ADDRESS}, links ADDRESS to the url mailto:ADDRESS
\providecommand*\email[1]{\href{mailto:#1}{#1}}
% Same as above, but pretty-prints ADDRESS in teletype fixed-width font
\renewcommand*\email[1]{\href{mailto:#1}{\texttt{#1}}}
%use for commenting
\usepackage{color}
\newcommand{\rwcomment}[1]{{\textcolor{blue}{\textsc{\textbf{[#1 --RW]}}}}}
% % knitr setup % %
<<setup, echo = F, message = F, warning = F>>=
knitr::opts_chunk$set(echo = F, cache = T, message = F, warning = F)
options(digits = 2) # round all R output to two digits
## clear environment
rm(list = ls())
## load packages
library(rstan) # interface to stan
library(tidyverse) # data manipulation and plotting
library(ggridges) # ridge plots for parameters
library(ggrepel) # repelled text for id restriction scatterplots
library(corrplot) # pretty correlation plots
## set seed for replication
set.seed(7912305)
## import data and models
invisible(lapply(list.files('Knitr Input', '.RData', full.names = T), load, .GlobalEnv))
## import functions
source('mcmcreg.R')
source('theme_rw.R')
## document level variables
ci_level <- .95
@
% % create averaged dataset for plots % %
<<averaged_estimates, warning = F>>=
## add up each element in list of data frames, then divide by length of list
PA_avg <- Reduce("+", lapply(PA_list, function(x) x %>% mutate_all(function(y) as.numeric(as.character(y))))) / length(PA_list)
## convet factors back to factors from numeric
PA_avg <- PA_avg %>% mutate_at(vars(sanction, mediation, pa_type), as.factor)
## get names from list of data frames since they don't vary
PA_avg[, c('Name', 'pa_name')] <- PA_list[[1]][, c('Name', 'pa_name')]
## drop imputation and id variables from mice since no longer needed
PA_avg[, c('.imp', '.id')] <- NULL
## shorten dayton agreement name
PA_names$pa_name <- as.character(PA_names$pa_name)
PA_names$pa_name[grep('Dayton', PA_names$pa_name)] <- 'Dayton Accords'
PA_names$pa_name <- as.factor(PA_names$pa_name)
@
% % used to access data and results throughout paper % %
<<results_names>>=
## hierarchical predictors/explanatory variables
covariates_nc <- cbind(model.matrix(~ sanction + mediation + intervention_imi,
data = PA_avg),
scale(PA_avg[, c('aidpct')]))[, -1]
colnames(covariates_nc) <- c('Sanction', 'Multilateral Sanction',
'Mediation', 'Regional Mediation',
'Intervention', 'Aid ($\\%$ GNI)')
covariates <- cbind(model.matrix(~ sanction + mediation + intervention_imi
+ as.factor(Inc) + CumInt + cold_war,
data = PA_avg),
scale(PA_avg[, c('aidpct', 'rpr_work',
'polity2')]))[, -1]
colnames(covariates) <- c('Sanction', 'Multilateral Sanction', 'Mediation',
'Regional Mediation', 'Intervention', 'Government',
'Cumulative Intensity', 'Post Cold War',
'Aid ($\\%$ GNI)', 'RPR', 'Polity2')
## indicators
indicators.mat <- as.matrix(PA[, provisions])
indicators.mat.full <- as.matrix(PA[, provisions_all])
# proper names for provisions
ind_names <- c('Ceasefire', 'Military Integration', 'Disarmament',
'Withdrawal', 'Political Parties', 'Government Integration',
'Civil service Integration', 'Elections', 'Interim Government',
'National Talks', 'Power Sharing', 'Amnesty for Rebels',
'Prisoner Release', 'National Reconciliation',
'Right of Return', 'Reaffirmation', 'Peacekeeping',
'Implementation')
ind_names_full <- c('Ceasefire', 'Military Integration', 'Disarmament',
'Withdrawal', 'Political Parties', 'Government Integration',
'Civil service Integration', 'Elections', 'Interim Government',
'National Talks', 'Power Sharing', 'Territorial Autonomy',
'Federalism', 'Independence', 'Referendum', 'Local power Sharing',
'Regional Development', 'Cultural Freedoms', 'Local Governance',
'Amnesty for Rebels', 'Prisoner Release', 'National Reconciliation',
'Right of Return', 'Reaffirmation', 'Outlining', 'Peacekeeping',
'Implementation')
colnames(indicators.mat) <- ind_names
colnames(indicators.mat.full) <- ind_names_full
## replace names in stanfits
names(agmt_add_ind)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_add_ind)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_add_ind)))] <-
c(colnames(covariates), '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_full_prob_sanc)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_full_prob_sanc)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_full_prob_sanc)))] <-
c('Sanction', 'Multilateral Sanction', '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_full_prob_med)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_full_prob_med)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_full_prob_med)))] <-
c('Mediation', 'Regional Mediation', '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_full_prob_mil)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_full_prob_mil)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_full_prob_mil)))] <-
c('Intervention', '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_full_prob_aid)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_full_prob_aid)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_full_prob_aid)))] <-
c('Aid ($\\%$ GNI)', '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_full_prob_nc)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_full_prob_nc)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_full_prob_nc)))] <-
c(colnames(covariates_nc), '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_full_prob)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_full_prob)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_full_prob)))] <-
c(colnames(covariates), '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_full_prob_id_1)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_full_prob_id_1)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_full_prob_id_1)))] <-
c(colnames(covariates), '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_full_prob_id_2)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_full_prob_id_2)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_full_prob_id_2)))] <-
c(colnames(covariates), '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_full_prob_id_3)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_full_prob_id_3)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_full_prob_id_3)))] <-
c(colnames(covariates), '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_response_nc)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_response_nc)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_response_nc)))] <-
c(colnames(covariates_nc), '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_response)[c(grep('beta', names(agmt_response)),
grep('mu_delta', names(agmt_response)))] <-
c(colnames(covariates), '$ \\mu_\\delta $')
names(agmt_irt)[grep('gamma', names(agmt_irt))] <- colnames(indicators.mat)
names(agmt_full_prob)[grep('gamma', names(agmt_full_prob))] <-
colnames(indicators.mat)
names(agmt_full_prob_all_inds)[grep('gamma', names(agmt_full_prob_all_inds))] <-
colnames(indicators.mat.full)
@
\begin{document}
\markboth{Williams, Gustafson, Gent, and Crescenzi}{Measuring Peace Agreement Strength}
\journalname{Draft Submission to Political Science Research and Methods}
\journalcopy{The European Political Science Association, 2018}
\fpage{X}
\lpage{XXX}
\journalvolume{X}
\journalissue{X}
\doinumber{XXX}
\title{A Latent Variable Approach to Measuring and Explaining Peace Agreement Strength\thanks{Rob Williams (jrw@live.unc.edu) Ph.D.\ Candidate, Daniel J.\ Gustafson (dgustaf@live.unc.edu) Ph.D.\ Candidate, Stephen E.\ Gent (gent@unc.edu) Associate Professor, Mark J.C.\ Crescenzi (crescenzi@unc.edu) Professor, Department of Political Science, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, 361 Hamilton Hall, Chapel Hill, NC 27599. An earlier version of this article was presented at the 2017 Annual Meeting of the International Studies Association, February 2017, Baltimore, MD, where Cliff Morgan provided valuable feedback. The authors also thank Elizabeth Menninga, Johannes Karreth, Ryan Bakker, Santiago Olivella, Layna Mosley, and two anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments which greatly improved the article.}}
\author{Rob Williams, Daniel J.\ Gustafson, Stephen E.\ Gent, and Mark J.C.\ Crescenzi}
\maketitle
% % abstract % %
\begin{abstract}
Much of the peace agreement durability literature assumes that stronger peace agreements are more likely to survive the trials of the post-conflict environment. This work does an excellent job identifying which provisions indicate that agreements are more likely to endure. However, there is no widely accepted way to directly measure the strength of agreements, and existing measures suffer from a lack of nuance or reliance on subjective weighting. We use a Bayesian item response theory model to develop a principled measure of the latent strength of peace agreements in civil conflicts from 1975-2005. We illustrate the measure's utility by exploring how various international factors such as sanctions and mediation contribute to the strength or weakness of agreements.
\end{abstract}
\doublespacing
% % body % %
\section{Introduction}
The study of civil conflict resolution is rife with weak peace agreements that were unable to bring closure to their respective conflicts. The Arusha Accords, signed in 1993 to end a three-year Rwandan Civil War, infamously failed to prevent the recurrence of conflict in Rwanda the following year. The Nairobi Agreement was supposed to end the Ugandan Civil War in 1985 but was never even implemented. The Lom\'e Peace Accord promised to end the Sierra Leone Civil War in 1999, but fighting continued until 2002. Almost every agreement signed by Afghanistan in the past three decades has been broken by one or more parties. Scholars and public officials deride these agreements and countless others as weak while praising long-lasting agreements such as the Good Friday Agreement as strong documents.
Yet, how much of the perception of civil peace agreements as weak or strong results from their observed duration? How could an agreement such as the Arusha Accords that was brokered as part of an extensive mediation process involving many third parties be so weak? Without being able to observe the counterfactual where Rwandan President Juv\'enal Habyarimana's plane was never shot down, we can know how much of the Accords' failure was due to his death rather than some inherent weakness in the agreement. This uncertainty suggests a need to measure the strength of an agreement separately from its duration.
There are several ways to measure the strength of a peace agreement, but each has its strengths and weaknesses. Given that even some strong peace agreements fail, the observed duration of an agreement is likely an imperfect indicator of its underlying strength. Specific characteristics of peace agreements give us some information about the strength or weakness of an agreement, but it is difficult to select a single characteristic that captures strength. An additive scale of provisions may be somewhat related to the strength of an agreement, but it weights all provisions equally. Treating all provisions the same is problematic because they likely do not all convey the same amount of information about agreement strength. Ceasefire provisions only result in a (potentially) temporary halt to the fighting, but power-sharing agreements require addressing underlying issues.
Given these issues, we take a new approach by treating agreement strength as a latent variable. Using Bayesian item response theory (IRT), we model the specific provisions within peace agreements as a function of an underlying latent agreement strength. We illustrate our new measurement strategy with an example of how scholars can apply it to substantive research questions by focusing on the question of whether external forces can influence peace agreement strength. The policy implications are clear: if outside actors can insert themselves and improve the strength of peace agreements, the chances of peace may improve. Alternatively, if external actors coerce belligerents to hastily sign agreements, the resulting document may fail to prevent future conflict.
\section{Measuring Peace Agreement Strength}
Peace agreements in civil war settings seek to end a conflict between a government and one or more nonstate actors. During negotiations, belligerents attempt to secure the greatest benefits for themselves while mitigating costs. Both parties have strong incentives to reach a settlement that halts the conflict because fighting inflicts great material costs. However, they may disagree about the specifics of an agreement. Negotiations, which may include third party mediators, attempt to craft an agreement that leads to peace and that both parties will sign. Therefore, the peace process seeks to find a mutually agreeable settlement that produces the highest likelihood of sustained peace.
We define peace agreement strength as the degree to which a negotiated settlement addresses parties' potential grievances by encoding specific provisions. This is similar to the way in which \citeasnoun{Fortna2003} defines agreement strength for international ceasefires. A strong agreement would address each of the potential causes of conflict, while a weak agreement would not. For rebel groups, fundamental grievances could stem from a desire for legal protections, political inclusion, or territorial autonomy. Governments generally seek a cessation of hostilities and disarmament by the rebels. A perfect agreement would address each of these concerns, while the worst possible agreement would solve none of these incompatibilities. Clearly, however, there are a range of possibilities between the best and worst potential agreements. We use the observable provisions within peace agreements to place them along this latent spectrum.
Consider the Arusha Accords signed in the summer of 1993 to end the three-year Rwandan Civil War. The talks were organized by the United States, France, and the Organisation of African Unity, and the resulting agreement contained several provisions considered important by existing literature on civil peace agreements. The Arusha Accords included provisions concerning the rule of law, repatriation of refugees, and the integration of rebels into the national army. The Rwandan Patriotic Front (RPF) was granted participation in the legislature and was given an equal number of cabinet posts as the former ruling party. While the agreement laid the groundwork for peace in Rwanda, it ultimately failed to prevent conflict recurrence, due in large part to the assassination of Rwandan President Juv\'enal Habyarimana. The eventual failure of the Arusha Accords shows that even agreements that are carefully crafted by well-resourced stakeholders can fail. The disconnect between the amount of effort that went into reaching the Arusha Accords and their quick failure suggests that we cannot judge the strength of a peace agreement solely by observing its duration.
To assess the quality of peace agreements, researchers have largely conducted statistical analyses with the duration of the agreement as the outcome variable. While duration is certainly an outcome of interest for scholars, there is not a one-to-one mapping of agreement strength to duration. The durability of any given peace agreement depends upon factors beyond the scope of the agreement itself. Fluctuation in the global economy might induce conflict regardless of a given settlement's strength, and the death of Habyarimana suggests that idiosyncratic factors can also play a large role in the fate of a given agreement. Agreement strength and duration are certainly correlated, but they are distinct outcomes.
Scholars have taken several alternative approaches to examining the quality of peace agreements. Some have focused on the effect of individual provisions such as power-sharing arrangements, the degree of agreement institutionalization, and the specificity of the actual document on agreement duration \cite{Hartzell2001,Hartzell2003,Werner2005}. While these studies have been foundational for understanding the importance of specific types of provisions, they focus on duration as the outcome of interest and cannot speak directly to the concept of agreement strength. \citeasnoun{Fortna2003} uses both subjective coding and an additive index of provisions to show a positive relationship between agreement strength and durability for international peace settlements. While her approaches represent attempts to systematically analyze agreement strength, they each suffer from potential biases. The subjective coding of peace agreements may be prone to researcher bias, and additive indices either treat indicators as equally important to the latent construct or suffer from disputes over the subjective weighting of different indicators \cite{Smith2018}. Finally, \citeasnoun{Badran2014} measures the strength of civil peace agreements using both an additive index and composite index produced via factor analysis. The composite index is an improvement on other attempts to characterize peace agreement strength but still suffers from weighting issues and fails to preserve the variability in the raw data. Our definition of peace agreement strength is based upon the completeness of the agreements themselves and is not necessarily related to an agreement's expected or actual duration.
\section{Agreement Strength as a Latent Variable}
We introduce a new measurement strategy to push forward the study and measurement of peace agreement strength by turning to item response theory, a method developed by the psychometrics literature. IRT models produce estimates of an underlying attribute, such as academic ability or quality of life, as represented by a series of observable indicators, such as questions on an exam or responses on a survey of health outcomes \cite{Rasch1980}. In the study of international relations and conflict, they have been used to measure states' nuclear capabilities \cite{Smith2018}, regime type \cite{Treier2008}, human rights practices \cite{Schnakenberg2014}, the depth of preferential trade agreements \cite{Dur2014}, and the scope of military alliance commitments \cite{Benson2016}. Scholars have used measurement models to improve theoretical accuracy, inference, and prediction \cite{Bakker2016,CarrollForthcoming,Fariss2014,Gray2012,Pemstein2010}.
For our measurement strategy, we employ the UCDP Peace Agreement Dataset \cite{Harbom2006}, which contains data on \Sexpr{ncol(indicators.mat.full)} different provisions for peace agreements in civil conflicts from 1975-2005. Figure \ref{fig:ind_corr} shows the correlation between each of the provisions in the dataset.
<<ind_corr, fig.cap = 'Correlation of all agreement provisions in the UCDP Peace Agreement Dataset \\cite{Harbom2006} for all agreements in our sample. Strength of correlation is represented by circle size and shade.', fig.scap = '', out.width = '.95\\linewidth', fig.pos = '!h', fig.align = 'center'>>=
corrplot(cor(indicators.mat.full), type = 'lower', cl.length = 9, tl.cex = .75,
tl.col = 'black', col = gray.colors(200, 1, .1, gamma = 2.2))
@
The simplest approach to measuring peace agreement strength is to add up the number of provisions present in a given agreement. However, this would be problematic as Figure \ref{fig:ind_corr} indicates that there is surprisingly little bivariate correlation between these provisions, with no two provisions having a correlation greater than $ \pm $ \Sexpr{max(abs(cor(indicators.mat.full) - diag(1, 27)))}. This pattern suggests that that not all provisions are related to the same aspect of peace agreements. No agreement has more than \Sexpr{max(apply(PA %>% select(cease:Co_impl), 1, sum))} out of \Sexpr{ncol(indicators.mat.full)} provisions, so adding all provisions together may result in biased measurements due to combining different concepts. Additionally, an additive index may mischaracterize the strength of an agreement by treating all provisions as equally meaningful.
Therefore, we treat peace agreement strength as a latent variable that is a function of the provisions an agreement contains. Peace agreements have numerous provisions such as power-sharing arrangements, integration of former combatants into the armed forces, and language recognition that can be viewed as observable indicators of an underlying agreement strength. Although \citeasnoun{Badran2014} finds that there are several dimensions to peace agreement strength, the peace agreement duration literature supports our decision to estimate a single latent measure of agreement strength. Based on the argument that, \emph{ceteris paribus}, stronger agreements should last longer \cite{Fortna2003}, we argue that because these provisions are associated with longer lasting agreements, they can potentially be thought of as indicators for a one-dimensional concept of agreement strength. Our model (which we discuss in more depth below) allows us to identify which indicators are positively related to our latent measure. Although we cannot be certain that our latent variable is capturing the strength of peace agreements, using indicators which are all positively correlated with agreement duration gives us confidence that we are indeed measuring agreement strength.\footnote{See the Supplemental Information for a list of all candidate provisions and citations for their positive effect on agreement duration.}
We suspect that there is some latent underlying strength to peace agreements and that this strength is expressed through the inclusion of these provisions. The stronger an agreement is, the more likely it is to have these provisions, which we refer to as indicators to be consistent with IRT literature. We estimate each indicator's relationship to the underlying dimension, which is the strength of a peace agreement. For each indicator, we also estimate a discrimination parameter that determines how much the presence or absence of an indicator tells us about the agreement's underlying strength. For instance, \Sexpr{round(mean(indicators.mat[,1]), digits = 2) * 100}\% of agreements in our sample contain ceasefire provisions, while only \Sexpr{round(mean(indicators.mat[,6]), digits = 2) * 100}\% of agreements have provisions for the integration of former rebels into the civil service.\footnote{Full summary statistics for agreement provisions are available in the Supplemental Information.} If both indicators are equally correlated with the latent strength of agreements, then the presence of civil service integration in a given agreement tells us more about its strength than the presence of ceasefire provisions does. Unlike the simple additive approach, the IRT model allows different indicators to contribute differentially to the strength of an agreement. Before we present results of our estimation, we briefly describe our initial application of the peace agreement strength measure: an analysis of how external actors influence peace agreement strength.
\section{Third Parties and Peace Agreement Strength}
To what extent can third party actors shape the strength of peace agreements? We explore this question as a first-pass illustration of our measure of agreement strength. We consider four mechanisms by which external influences can affect the strength of a peace agreement. The first two, economic sanctions and threats of foreign aid revocation, can be thought of as indirect mechanisms sometimes used in cases of manipulative mediation or directive mediation \cite{Beardsley2006,Touval1985}. The second two, mediation and military intervention, are more direct ways for outside parties to become involved in conflict management.
We argue that states subject to economic sanctions are more likely to sign weak agreements. Economic coercion through sanctions shifts the incentives of the government, encouraging them to sign agreements they otherwise would not. An external state may threaten or impose sanctions to encourage the target state to produce a peaceful settlement. Given the punishing costs that sanctions can generate, governments may have an incentive to sign an agreement just to get relief from the sanctions. Consequently, governments may not be focused on signing the `best' peace agreements they can when under economic sanctions. After the United States threatened to impose economic sanctions \cite{Anna2015} and a UN arms embargo \cite{Nichols2015} on South Sudan unless they ended their civil war, President Salva Kiir signed a peace treaty despite ``serious reservations'' \cite{Dumo2015}. Kiir's concerns illustrate that he was aware of the dangers of the agreement, even going so far as to warn that ``a poor agreement could backfire on the region.'' Crafting a strong peace agreement is a long and contentious process that involves bringing together all relevant stakeholders and attempting to reach a compromise that satisfies many different parties \cite{Fortna2003}. Sanctioning states may underestimate the complexity of the situation and push for a faster resolution, leading to a weaker agreement.
In addition to cutting off access to international trade and other financial flows, outside actors can also restrict government finances by suspending foreign aid payments. States that are dependent on this aid will be particularly receptive to these threats. Foreign aid is often allocated strategically, with countries receiving increased aid for democratizing \cite{Alesina2000} or higher numbers of World Bank projects during their term on the UN security council \cite{Dreher2009}. Unfortunately, we cannot systematically observe threats to revoke aid the way we can with sanctions. Instead, we must settle for the degree to which a state is dependent on foreign aid. While imperfect, this measure captures the ability of third parties to lean on governments to sign peace agreements in civil wars. Thus, peace agreements signed in states that highly depend on foreign aid will be weaker than agreements signed in other states.
While economic coercion through sanctions and foreign aid revocation should lead a peace agreement to be weaker on average, the relationship between mediation and agreement strength is more nuanced. In theory, mediation efforts should allow allow warring parties to come together and have structured conversations in an attempt to uncover each belligerent's grievances and craft a peace agreement that directly addresses them. In reality, mediation may actually serve as a substitution for full resolution \cite{Werner2005} and can leave dyads worse-off in the long-term because of the artificial incentives that it imposes \cite{Beardsley2008}. Thus, we have reason to expect that mediation will produce weaker agreements on average. Mediation is most effective in generating strong agreements when mediators and belligerents work in an environment of trust and have strong incentives to contribute to the peace process, such as when regional organizations serve as mediating parties \cite{Gartner2011}. Individual mediators within regional organizations are likely to share important political and cultural characteristics with the belligerents, and these similar identities can increase actors' trust during negotiations \cite{Olson2002,Wehr1991}. States in close proximity also have strong incentives to prevent the spread of conflict \cite{Kadera1998}. Because regional organizations as mediators facilitate trust and have material incentives to mitigate the likelihood of conflict recurrence, peace agreements signed in their presence will be stronger on average.
Intervention into an ongoing conflict can drastically increase its duration \cite{Regan2002} by introducing new veto players with different preferences than the primary combatants \cite{Cunningham2006}. This effect may also lower the quality of any negotiated settlements reached in the conflict through two possible pathways. First, any agreement reached has to also satisfy the demands of external states in addition to those of the domestic combatants. This could result in weaker agreements that do not address the incompatibility between the initial combatants. Second, interveners who wish to extricate themselves from the conflict may push combatants to sign agreements, allowing them to withdraw. These agreements may be weaker than those signed more organically in conflicts without an internationalized dimension.
\section{Model} \label{section:model}
We now turn to our measurement model of agreement strength. Ultimately, we want to use our estimates of peace agreement strength to understand why some agreements are weak and others are strong. As estimates, these values of agreement strength are uncertain, and we must account for the uncertainty in our analysis.\footnote{The conventional procedure in this situation is to estimate two separate models: a measurement model to capture the latent construct and a regression model to explain variation in it. Unfortunately, this method ignores the uncertainty in the latent estimates. One way to overcome this limitation is to draw multiple samples from the posterior distribution of a latent construct and use them as the response variable instead of just the point estimate. For example, \citeasnoun{Fariss2014} includes both the posterior mean and standard deviation of his latent human rights respect score so that users of the data can carry out this process.} In the best case scenario where this error is truly random, ignoring it will not bias coefficients but will bias standard errors downward. If it is not random, then ignoring it can bias both coefficient estimates and standard errors. Our approach accounts for both possibilities by estimating what \citeasnoun[277-295]{Armstrong2014} call a ``full probability model,'' which allows the observed indicators for each agreement to determine the measured strength of the agreement while also letting the conflict-level explanatory variables explain variation in this strength across agreements. By including explanations for agreement strength in the model, we are able to share information across observations. Intuitively, two agreements signed at the end of territorial conflicts should be more similar than an agreement signed at the end of a territorial conflict and one signed at the end of a governmental conflict. Estimating a full probability model lets us include the type of conflict an agreement was signed in, allowing us to incorporate this information into our estimates of agreement strength.
This model takes uncertainty around the estimated latent agreement strengths into account when estimating the effect of sanctions on agreement strength. This leads to a more conservative analysis because the explanatory variables have to explain variation in a range of agreement strengths instead of just a single value. This leads to more uncertainty in our estimates, so a strong effect for our explanatory variables should be interpreted as compelling support for our hypotheses.
Our full probability model is presented in Equations \ref{irt_start}-\ref{irt_end}, where $ i $ indexes agreements, $ j $ indexes provisions, and $ k $ indexes conflicts. The observed indicators $ \mathbf{X} $ are a function of latent agreement strength $ \bm{\theta} $, multiplied by the discrimination parameters $ \bm{\gamma} $, minus the difficulty parameter $ \bm{\alpha} $. The discrimination parameter describes how much the presence of a given provisions tells us about the strength of an agreement, and the difficulty parameter tells us how strong an agreement must be to have a given parameter. Our explanatory variables $ \mathbf{Z} $ enter into the model as hierarchical predictors on the mean of each agreement's strength, $ \bm{\theta} $, with regression coefficients $ \bm{\beta} $. In addition to these explanatory variables, the mean of $ \bm{\theta} $ also includes a random intercept $ \bm{\delta} $ by conflict, to account for a lack of independence between multiple agreements signed in the same conflict. The means of $ \bm{\alpha} $, $ \bm{\gamma} $, and $ \bm{\delta} $ have normal priors with diffuse normal hyperpriors, and the standard deviations of $ \bm{\alpha} $, $ \bm{\gamma} $, $ \bm{\delta} $, and $ \bm{\theta} $ have diffuse half Cauchy hyperpriors. This choice of priors reflects our lack of theoretically driven expectations for the effect of our predictors. The regression coefficients $ \bm{\beta} $ have diffuse Student T priors.\footnote{The separate measurement and regression model approach, which we refer to as a standalone IRT model, splits Equations \ref{irt_start} and \ref{lm_sep} and their respective priors into two distinct models run sequentially. We estimate this model and present results in the Supplemental Information, finding that coefficient estimates are substantively similar but with smaller credible intervals because this specification ignores the uncertainty in our latent estimates.}
{
\singlespacing
\begin{subequations}
\begin{align}
x_{ij} &\sim \text{Bernoulli}(\gamma_j \theta_i - \alpha_j) \label{irt_start} \\
\theta_i &\sim \mathcal{N}(\delta_k + \mathbf{z}_i \bm{\beta}, \sigma_{\theta}) \label{lm_sep}\\
\bm{\alpha} &\sim \mathcal{N}(\mu_\alpha, \sigma_\alpha) \\
\bm{\gamma} &\sim \mathcal{N}(\mu_\gamma, \sigma_\gamma) \\
\bm{\delta} &\sim \mathcal{N}(\mu_\delta, \sigma_\delta) \\
\mu_\alpha,\mu_\gamma &\sim \mathcal{N}(0, 25) \\
\mu_\delta &\sim \mathcal{N}(0, 5) \\
\sigma_{\alpha},\sigma_\gamma,\sigma_\delta,\sigma_\theta &\sim \text{hCauchy}(0, 5) \\
\bm{\beta} &\sim t(4, 0, 1) \label{irt_end}
\end{align}
\end{subequations}
}
The standard IRT model is unidentified due to possibility of infinite rotations which could fit the data, so we place two identification restrictions on the model \cite{Bafumi2005}. First, the sign on the discrimination parameter $ \bm{\gamma} $ is constrained to be positive, as all included indicators are coded so that their presence indicates a stronger agreement, while their absence denotes a weaker one. We first estimate our measurement model on \emph{all} agreement provisions and then evaluate how well this assumption fits our data. Second, to identify our model, we fix the values of $ \bm{\theta} $ for two peace agreements: the DUP/SPLM Sudan Peace Agreement between the Democratic Unionist Party and the Sudanese People's Liberation Movement, and the Tripoli Agreement between the government of the Philippines and the Moro National Liberation Front.
Setting the value of $ \theta $ for these two agreements anchors the latent construct and ensures that our results are `correctly' oriented, with stronger agreements above zero, and weaker ones below. We set $ \theta = -1 $ for the DUP/SPLM Sudan Peace Agreement because it has only \Sexpr{PA_avg[PA_avg$pa_name == 'DUP/SPLM Sudan Peace Agreement', 'add_ind']} provisions, and we set $ \theta = 1 $ for the Tripoli Agreement because it has \Sexpr{PA_avg[PA_avg$pa_name == 'Tripoli Agreement', 'add_ind']} provisions. Because our model defines stronger agreements as those with more provisions, the DUP/SPLM Sudan Peace Agreement can serve as a `weak' anchor, while the Tripoli Agreement is a `strong' one. Fixing the value of $\theta$ for these two agreements merely orients our latent scale; it does not determine the strength of these two agreements.
\subsection{Agreement Strength Measurement} \label{section:strength_measurement}
Before presenting the estimates produced by our model, we pause to assess the validity of our measurement strategy. We first estimate a model that includes all provisions as indicators in the measurement model, with their presence coded 1 and their absence coded 0. The identification restriction that $ \bm{\gamma} $ must be positive is based on the assumption that all indicators have a positive effect on the underlying quantity. To verify this, we assess the densities of the indicator discrimination parameters to ensure that this is a reasonable constraint \cite[178]{Bafumi2005}. We exclude indicators whose densities are concentrated at zero.\footnote{These indicators likely map onto a different latent quantity than that represented by indicators with $ \bm{\gamma} $ values $\gg 0$. See the Supplemental Information for a full discussion of this process.}
We next present the measurement model's difficulty and discrimination parameters, $ \bm{\alpha} $ and $ \bm{\gamma} $, from the full probability model estimated using only relevant provisions. Examining these parameters helps us to understand what each provision tells us about the latent strength of a peace agreement. This is an important exercise because there is no simple test to check whether the latent construct that we have created actually aligns with our concept of peace agreement strength. Instead, we need to see whether the parameters in the model align with our theoretical expectations of how observed indicators should relate to strong and weak agreements.
<<irt_params_tab>>=
# get posterior means of IRT parameters; for in-text references now, print in appendix
irt_params <- data.frame(summary(agmt_full_prob, pars = 'alpha')$summary[, 'mean'],
summary(agmt_full_prob, pars = 'gamma')$summary[, 'mean'])
## rename columns alpha and gamma
colnames(irt_params) <- c('$\\alpha$', '$\\gamma$')
rownames(irt_params) <- colnames(indicators.mat)
@
<<irt_params, fig.align = 'center', fig.height = 4, fig.cap = "Difficulty ($ \\bm{\\alpha} $) and discrimination ($ \\bm{\\gamma} $) parameters in the measurement model. The difficulty parameter controls the location of the item characteristic curve's inflection point, while the discrimination parameter controls the slope.">>=
## extract mean and credible interval for difficulty and discrimination parameters
irt_params_range <- data.frame(summary(agmt_full_prob,
pars = c('alpha', 'gamma'),
probs = c(.5 - ci_level/2,
.5 + ci_level/2))$summary[, c(1, 4:5)])
## create variable of provision name for plotting
irt_params_range$variable <- factor(rep(rownames(irt_params_range)[19:36], times = 2), levels = ind_names)
## reverse order of provision names to match tables
irt_params_range$variable <- factor(irt_params_range$variable, levels = rev(levels(irt_params_range$variable)))
## create variable for faceting
irt_params_range$disc <- rep(0:1, each = nrow(irt_params_range) / 2)
## rename credible interval columns for dynamic referencing in ggplot
colnames(irt_params_range)[2:3] <- c('low', 'high')
## coefficient plot of difficulty and discrimination parameters
ggplot(irt_params_range, aes(x = variable, y = mean, ymin = low, ymax = high)) +
geom_hline(yintercept = 0, lty = 2, color = 'gray40') +
geom_pointrange() +
facet_grid(~ disc, labeller = as_labeller(c('0' = 'Difficulty',
'1' = 'Discrimination')),
scales = 'free') +
coord_flip() +
labs(x = '', y = '') +
theme_rw() +
theme(axis.ticks.y = element_blank(),
axis.ticks.x = element_line(color = 'gray40'))
@
Figure \ref{fig:irt_params} presents the posterior means of the difficulty and discrimination parameters in the measurement model. The higher the value of the difficulty parameter, the higher the baseline level of agreement strength required for a provision to be present. This means that an agreement has to be very strong for power sharing or civil service integration provisions to be included, but even a very weak agreement is likely to have ceasefire provisions due to its low parameter estimate of \Sexpr{irt_params['Ceasefire', 1]}. Ceasefire arrangements are the most common provisions, appearing in \Sexpr{round(mean(indicators.mat[,1]), digits = 2) * 100}\% of agreements. Given their prevalence, it makes sense that agreements do not have to be very strong to include ceasefire provisions.
The higher the value of the discrimination parameter, the steeper the item characteristic curve (ICC) for that provision. Steeper ICCs indicate provisions that are better discriminators between strong and weak agreements. The provision with the highest discrimination is \Sexpr{tolower(rownames(irt_params[which(irt_params[, 2] == max(irt_params[, 2])), ]))} with a parameter estimate of \Sexpr{max(irt_params[, 2])}. This means that \Sexpr{tolower(rownames(irt_params[which(irt_params[, 2] == max(irt_params[, 2])), ]))} are the best provision for discriminating between weak and strong agreements. Given their frequency, ceasefire provisions are a surprisingly good discriminator, with an estimate of \Sexpr{irt_params['Ceasefire', 2]}. Taken together, these two parameter estimates mean that any agreements without ceasefire provisions are exceptionally weak.
Power sharing agreements have a very high difficulty parameter value of \Sexpr{irt_params['Power Sharing', 1]} and a relatively high discrimination parameter value of \Sexpr{irt_params['Power Sharing', 2]}. This means that agreements must be strong to have power sharing provisions, and that the presence or absence of power sharing provisions tells us much about the strength of a given agreement. These parameter values align with the findings from the peace agreement duration literature that power sharing agreements have a significant positive impact on the duration of peace \cite{Hartzell2003}.
The relationship between the provisions included in peace agreements and their underlying strength revealed by these parameters largely aligns with our expectations. As such, we can be confident that our latent construct really does reflect what we would analytically describe as the strength of a peace agreement. We note that the correlation between our latent measure of agreement strength and the comprehensiveness of an agreement is \Sexpr{cor(PA_avg$full.mean, -as.numeric(PA_avg$pa_type))}. This measure of comprehensiveness comes from the peace agreements data \cite{Harbom2006} and is a three point ordinal variable denoting whether an agreement is a process, partial, or full agreement, with more comprehensive agreements coded higher. More comprehensive agreements should address more of the underlying differences behind a conflict and should be stronger as a result. This \Sexpr{ifelse(cor(PA_avg$full.mean, -as.numeric(PA_avg$pa_type)) > 0, 'positive', 'correlation is negative -- you have a problem!')} correlation suggests that our latent construct is properly oriented so that higher values represent stronger agreements.
The correlation between our latent strength measure and a simple additive index of provisions is \Sexpr{cor(PA_avg$full.mean, PA_avg$add_ind)}. While stronger than the correlation with the comprehensiveness measure, this correlation is still not perfect. Mathematically, differences between the two can be explained by the varied difficulty and discrimination parameters in the measurement model. Substantively, this means that the nuance introduced by a measurement model tells us more about the underlying strength of a given agreement because it accounts for the fact that not all provisions are equally representative of strength. Just as an additive index is contains more relevant information than a three point ordinal variable, our latent strength measure is a similar improvement.
Figure \ref{fig:strength_dotplot} presents estimates for all agreements in our sample, along with associated measures of uncertainty.\footnote{The agreement strength values presented here are averages of the results from five imputed datasets.} The two point estimates with no uncertainty are the agreements whose strength we fix to identify and orient our model.\footnote{Agreement strength estimates from the standalone IRT model are presented in the Supplemental Information. The extra information included in the full probability model produces a much larger range of agreement strength values, allowing for more meaningful inference on the effect of international involvement on agreement strength.} The distribution of agreements along this latent scale is relatively invariant to different choices of agreements for the strong and weak identification restriction.\footnote{See the Supplemental Information for results using alternative agreements to identify the model.} Interestingly, two frequently discussed agreements in the literature have opposite positions from what we would expect. The Arusha Accords are often held up as an example of a weak agreement that failed, leading to the resumption of hostilities and large-scale civilian killings. However, in our scale, they are one of the strongest peace agreements. The Good Friday Agreement, which ended the Troubles in Northern Ireland, is frequently considered to be a strong agreement responsible for the long-lasting peace. Yet it is in the lower half of the spectrum. We return to this puzzling finding further in our discussion.
<<strength_dotplot, echo = F, warning = F, fig.cap = 'The posterior mean of latent agreement strength is represented by the points, while the lines denote 95\\% credible intervals. The observations without any uncertainty are the DUP/SPLM Sudan Peace Agreement and the Good Friday Agreement, whose values are fixed and thus not estimated.', fig.height = 3, fig.width = 6, fig.pos = 'h!', fig.align = 'center'>>=
## create object with peace agreements and estimated strengths
agmt_measures_full <- cbind(PA_names, summary(agmt_full_prob, pars = 'theta',
probs = c(.5 - ci_level/2,
.5 + ci_level/2))$summary[, c(1, 4:5)])
## combine agreement names and dates with estimated strengths
strength_full <- merge(agmt_measures_full, PA_avg[, c('PAID', 'Year')], sort = F)
## sort from weakest to strongest agreement
strength_full <- strength_full[order(strength_full$mean), ]
## create index variable to present shift between IRT models
strength_full$index <- 1:nrow(strength_full)
## rename upper and lower uncertainty bound for intervals
colnames(strength_full)[7:8] <- c('int_low', 'int_hi')
## convert agreement names to character for removal
strength_full$pa_name_dot <- as.character(strength_full$pa_name)
## remove all agreement names except for illustrative cases
strength_full$pa_name_dot[!strength_full$pa_name_dot %in% c('DUP/SPLM Sudan Peace Agreement',
'Tripoli Agreement',
'The Good Friday Agreement',
'Arusha Accords')] <- ''
## plot latent strengths
ggplot(strength_full, aes(x = mean, y = index, label = pa_name_dot)) +
geom_segment(aes(x = int_low, xend = int_hi, y = index,
yend = index), col = 'gray50', alpha = .65,
data = strength_full) +
geom_point(aes(), col = 'gray50', alpha = .5) +
geom_vline(xintercept = 0, linetype = 5, col = 'gray40') +
theme_bw() +
geom_text_repel(size = 2.5, point.padding = .25, box.padding = 2.5,
min.segment.length = 0, segment.color = 'gray40', na.rm = T, seed = 5) +
theme(plot.background = element_blank(),
panel.grid.minor = element_blank(),
panel.grid.major = element_blank(),
panel.border = element_blank(),
axis.title.y = element_blank(),
axis.ticks.y = element_blank(),
axis.text.y = element_blank(),
axis.ticks.x = element_line(color = 'gray40'),
axis.title.x = element_blank())
@
<<max_comps>>=
## get two peace agreements w/ most provisions
PA_max <- PA_avg[which(PA_avg$add_ind == max(PA_avg$add_ind)), ]
## calculate number of provisions shared by agreements
shared_provs <- sum((PA_max %>% select(cease:Co_impl))[1,] -
(PA_max %>% select(cease:Co_impl))[2,] == 0)
## convert accent to tex; done here to avoid problem w/ inline R code
max_pa_name_short <- sub('ú', "\\\\'{u}", PA_max$pa_name[1])
@
Comparing estimates of agreement strength from the full probability model and the additive index demonstrates the benefits of our approach. We specifically look at the two agreements with the most provisions, and hence, the highest estimated strength with an additive index. \Sexpr{max_pa_name_short} in \Sexpr{sub(':.*', '', PA_max$Name[1])} and the \Sexpr{PA_max$pa_name[2]} in \Sexpr{sub(':.*', '', PA_max$Name[2])} both have \Sexpr{PA_max$add_ind[1]} of the total \Sexpr{ncol(indicators.mat.full)} provisions in the data. An additive index approach would lead us to conclude that these two agreements have similar, if not identical, strengths. In fact, the full probability model estimates that the former has a strength of \Sexpr{PA_max$full.mean[1]} while the latter has one of \Sexpr{PA_max$full.mean[2]}. The two agreements share only \Sexpr{shared_provs} of \Sexpr{PA_max$add_ind[1]} provisions, and the provisions present in the former include national talks and civil service integration, which are two of the provisions with the highest discrimination parameter estimates, so their absence from the \Sexpr{PA_max$pa_name[2]} indicates that it is weaker.
These two agreements demonstrate the nuance introduced by our measurement model compared to a simple additive index. Agreements can have the same number of provisions, but if they have different provisions, their strengths may radically vary. Our measurement model thus allows us to identify differences between agreements with the same number of provisions, which we cannot do with an additive index. Even when two agreements share the same provisions, our full probability model offers advantages over a traditional IRT model. While the agreements may share the same provisions, they will have different predictor values, and so they will receive different strength values.
\subsection{Explanatory and Control Variables}
We rely on the Threat and Imposition of Economic Sanctions (TIES) dataset to measure instances of economic sanctions \cite{Morgan2009,Morgan2014a}. We create a categorical variable that takes on a value of 0 for \emph{no sanction}, 1 for a \emph{unilateral sanction} episode, and 2 for a \emph{multilateral sanction} episode. To measure whether an agreement was signed as part of a mediation process or not, we use the Civil Wars Mediation (CWM) dataset \cite{DeRouen2011,DeRouen2012} to code a categorical variable that takes on a value of 0 for \emph{no mediation}, 1 for \emph{mediation}, and 2 for \emph{regional mediation}. Any agreement that is coded as a 1 on this variable indicates that mediation occurred, but there was no regional organization that participated as a mediator. We operationalize a state's dependence on foreign aid using the fraction of a state's GNI that comes from official development assistance \cite{WorldBank2018} to construct the variable \emph{aid}. To determine whether a conflict is subject to third party military intervention, we use the International Military Intervention (IMI) Dataset \cite{Pickering2009} to construct the dummy variable \emph{intervention}, which denotes whether foreign military forces were engaged in an intervention in the country on the date an agreement was signed.
In addition to our explanatory variables, we employ a number of control variables to account for other sources of variation in peace agreement strength. To control for the possibility that stronger states will sign stronger agreements, we use relative political reach (\emph{RPR}), from the Relative Political Capacity data \cite{Arbetman1997,Kugler2012}. We also control for the possibility that conflict-level characteristics can affect the strength of agreements signed by belligerents by including a measure of whether the underlying incompatibility within a conflict was over government or territory. Because mediation efforts often target the most intractable cases \cite{Greig2005,Gartner2006}, we include whether the conflict's \emph{cumulative intensity} has exceeded 1,000 battle-deaths at the time of the agreement's signing \cite{Gleditsch2002,Themner2014}. Due to decreasing security commitments after the end of the Cold War, Western governments can more credibly threaten the withdrawal of foreign aid \cite{Bearce2010}, so we include a dummy variable measuring whether an agreement was signed \emph{post cold war}. Following standard practice, we also measure the government's \emph{polity2} score \cite{Marshall2014} at the time of agreement signing.
\section{Results}
In this section we present and discuss results from our full probability model. Due to missingness in the explanatory variables, we generate \Sexpr{PA_mi$m} imputed datasets, run two chains on each, and then perform inference on all \Sexpr{length(agmt_full_prob@stan_args)} chains pooled together, averaging over the uncertainty in different imputed values \cite[217-218]{Little2002}. We run each chain for \Sexpr{prettyNum(agmt_full_prob@stan_args[[1]][[5]], big.mark = ',')} warmup iterations, followed by \Sexpr{prettyNum(agmt_full_prob@stan_args[[1]][[2]] - agmt_full_prob@stan_args[[1]][[5]], big.mark = ',')} sampling iterations; all results presented are from the sampling iterations. All continuous predictors are centered and scaled to aid with mixing.\footnote{Standard diagnostics, available in the Supplemental Information, provide good evidence that our Markov chains have achieved convergence and explored the full parameter space of the posterior distribution}
\subsection{Agreement Strength Explanation} \label{section:strength_explanation}
We summarize the samples from the posterior distribution for our full probability model in Table \ref{table:main}. The design matrix $ \mathbf{Z} $ in the regression model does not contain an intercept term, so we include the mean of the random intercept $ \mu_\delta $ in our results as the grand mean of the regression model. We present the posterior mean and \Sexpr{ci_level * 100}\% credible interval for each predictor. Models 1-4 include our explanatory variables individually, while Model 5 includes all explanatory variables. Model 6 adds our control variables. The results are relatively stable across all specifications.
<<table_main, results = 'asis'>>=
mcmcreg(list(agmt_full_prob_sanc, agmt_full_prob_med, agmt_full_prob_mil,
agmt_full_prob_aid, agmt_full_prob_nc, agmt_full_prob),
pars = c('beta', 'mu_delta'), ci = ci_level,
caption = 'Posterior density of parameter estimates for explanatory variables. The point estimates are posterior means and represent the most probable value for the relationship between each variable and agreement strength.',
label = 'table:main', reorder_coef = c(1, 2, 4:(ncol(covariates) + 1), 3),
sideways = T)
@
<<ridgeplot, message = F, fig.cap = "Posterior distributions for parameter estimates of our explanatory variables. Each shaded line represents a different chain, and the overlap between the lines indicates that the chains have converged to the stationary distribution. Although we display only our explanatory variables, these results are from Model 6 with control variables included.", fig.width = 6, fig.height = 3, fig.align = 'center', fig.pos = '!h'>>=
ridge_ggs <- ggmcmc::ggs(As.mcmc.list(agmt_full_prob), family = 'beta')
## drop control variables
ridge_ggs <- ridge_ggs[ridge_ggs$Parameter %in% paste('beta[', c(1:5, 9), ']', sep = ''), ]
ridge_ggs$Parameter <- factor(ridge_ggs$Parameter,
levels = rev(levels(ridge_ggs$Parameter)))
ggplot(ridge_ggs, aes(x = value, y = Parameter, color = as.factor(Chain))) +
geom_vline(xintercept = 0, linetype = 5, col = 'gray40') +
geom_density_ridges(fill = NA, rel_min_height = .01, scale = 1.25,
show.legend = F) +
labs(x = '', y = '') +
scale_color_grey() +
theme_bw() +
scale_y_discrete(labels = rev(sub('\\$\\\\%\\$', '%',
colnames(covariates)[c(1:5, 9)]))) +
coord_cartesian(xlim = c(-3, 3)) +
theme(plot.background = element_blank(),
panel.grid.minor = element_blank(),
panel.grid.major = element_blank(),
panel.border = element_blank(),
axis.ticks.y = element_blank(),
axis.ticks.x = element_line(color = 'gray40'))
@
As we do not have a parametric hypothesis test threshold to evaluate the significance of our results, we want to be able to assess the effect magnitude and direction for each predictor. To accomplish this, we present our results graphically in Figure \ref{fig:ridgeplot}.
<<res_prob>>=
beta_samps <- as.data.frame(agmt_full_prob, pars = 'beta')
@
We find support for some of our expectations pertaining to the relationship between international third-party actions and civil peace agreement strength. The posterior means of both \emph{sanctions} and \emph{multilateral sanctions} are negative. The model suggests that the probability that \emph{sanctions} are associated with weaker peace agreements relative to \emph{no sanctions} is \Sexpr{mean(beta_samps$Sanction < 0)}, and the same probability for \emph{multilateral sanctions} is \Sexpr{mean(beta_samps$`Multilateral Sanction` < 0)}. However, given that the $\bm{\beta}$ distributions for these two variables have substantial density around 0, we are unable to state that economic sanctions or the threat thereof lead agreements to be weaker on average.
We find that \emph{mediation} has a negative relationship with agreement strength relative to \emph{no mediation} with probability \Sexpr{mean(beta_samps$Mediation < 0)}, while \emph{regional mediation} is positive relative to \emph{no mediation} with probability \Sexpr{mean(beta_samps$`Regional Mediation` > 0)}. This lends support for our expectations, although there is a large amount of uncertainty over \emph{regional mediation} relative to \emph{no mediation}. Importantly, however, there is a substantial difference between the posterior estimates for \emph{mediation} and \emph{regional mediation}, providing evidence that the latter is associated with stronger agreements than the former. The model indicates that the probability that \emph{military intervention} is positive is \Sexpr{mean(beta_samps$Intervention > 0)}, contradicting our expectation. Finally, our model suggests that an increase in \emph{foreign aid} dependence has a probability of \Sexpr{mean(beta_samps$`Aid ($\\%$ GNI)` > 0)} of being associated with stronger agreements. This finding does not conform with our theoretical expectations, but may be due to measurement error because we are unable to directly measure the true concept of interest---threat of foreign aid revocation.
Although we find some support for our expectations, we are unable to find strong associations between the presence of economic sanctions or military intervention and the strength of an agreement. These null findings are surprising given the abundance of literature that shows how states are able to exercise some control over foreign countries' domestic politics by using these tools. Additionally, we find that regional mediation is associated with stronger agreements than non-regional mediation, but our model suggests that there is very little difference between the strengths of agreements associated with regional mediation and no mediation. The findings indicate the need for more research on the determinants of agreement strength.
\section{Discussion}
Our analysis suggests a need for more consideration of the relationship between provisions, agreement strength, and the duration of peace agreements. We find that agreement strength---treated as a function of the provisions within the document---is negatively correlated with agreement duration ($\rho = \Sexpr{sprintf("%.2f", round(cor(PA_avg$full.mean, PA_avg$duration), 2))}$). This unexpected negative correlation between agreement strength and duration raises an important question about the validity of our measure. Given that the majority of the literature argues that stronger agreements should last longer, one possibility is that we are not correctly measuring agreement strength. Another possibility, however, is that stronger agreements present belligerents with more encoded constraints over their future behavior, and parties to the agreement are more likely to renege when there are numerous provisions. Additionally, measurement error may exist in the duration of peace agreements because the coding rules used to determine whether or not an agreement has ended are imprecise.
One common validation approach in this situation is to replicate existing studies using the new measure \cite{Smith2018,CarrollForthcoming}. Unfortunately, we are unable to replicate a previous study because, to the best of the authors' knowledge, this study represents the first attempt to systematically measure the strength of peace agreements using more than one or two provisions. In related work, \citeasnoun{Hartzell1999} codes the institutionalization of a peace agreement by determining whether it has rules regarding the use of coercive power, the distribution of political power, and the structuring of distributive policy. \citeasnoun{Hartzell2003} use political, military, territorial, and economic power-sharing to code the institutionalization of an agreement. It is not clear how to translate these coding rules to the provisions in the UCDP Peace Agreement Dataset, making comparison with these studies difficult. \citeasnoun{Fortna2003} constructs a subjective measure of agreement strength, as well as an additive index of agreement provisions, but her sample is of interstate conflicts, so we cannot make comparisons to our measure of intrastate conflict agreement strength. Instead, our contribution lies in opening up new avenues of research into conflict resolution, which we discuss below.
Although we are unable to replicate previous work, we believe that the surprising latent strength values of some agreements in our sample offer insight into how we study conflict resolution. The position of the Arusha Accords near the top of our scale and the Good Friday Agreement below the middle are particularly curious. The model implies that the Arusha Accords are strong partially because several of their provisions have very high discrimination parameters in our measurement model such as military integration, peacekeeping operations, and elections. Thus, the agreement encoded a number of theoretically peace-improving provisions despite its short existence. Our model suggests that the Good Friday Agreement is not strong despite its persistence because it does not contain a provision for a ceasefire, which is relatively easy to come by and tells us quite a bit about the latent strength of an agreement. Additionally, several of the provisions in the Good Friday Agreement such as those pertaining to cultural freedoms and a referendum were dropped because we deemed them to relate to a different latent dimension. This second dimension of peace agreements presents one interesting avenue for future research.
\section{Conclusion}
By employing Bayesian IRT, we are able to measure and explain the strength of peace agreements without having to rely on simple additive indices or subjective codings of agreement strength. Our measure exhibits substantial variation, even among agreements with the same number of provisions, indicating that it is better at capturing qualitative differences between agreements. In contrast to subjectively weighting specific provisions, a Bayesian IRT model of agreement strength offers a principled way to exclude irrelevant provisions while allowing the data to determine the relationship between individual provisions and agreement strength.
We believe that our measurement strategy improves upon current operationalizations of peace agreement strength, but the decision about which measure to use is fundamentally dependent on the research question at hand. Our measure is essentially a consolidation of the information present in peace agreements that pertain to a single dimension of peace agreement strength. Because of this, this measure is useful when research questions focus on the strength of negotiated settlements as a concept. Our measure is not well suited for research questions that are concerned with the causes or effects of individual provisions present in peace agreements. Additionally, our measure of peace agreement strength cannot speak to issues of implementation or enforcement outside of what is contained in the provisions. While these research questions require different measures, our measurement strategy is appropriate for a large number of questions pertaining to an agreement's underlying strength.
The ability to reliably measure the strength of such small numbers of agreements opens up many new opportunities to ask questions researchers could not previously evaluate systematically. Are stronger peace agreements more likely to see full implementation \cite{Joshi2013,Joshi2015} of their various elements? Do different types of mediator leverage \cite{Reid2017} lead to stronger or weaker agreements? Do biased mediators \cite{Svensson2009} lead to stronger agreements than unbiased ones? Do multilateral mediation efforts \cite{Bohmelt2012} produce stronger agreements than unilateral ones? While we focus on intrastate conflicts due to the wealth of mediation data in the CWM data, analyses which employ explanatory variables also available for interstate conflicts can utilize all \Sexpr{nrow(rio::import('Datasets/124926_1peace-agreements-1975-2011.xls'))} agreements in the UCDP Peace Agreement Dataset. Such analyses could explore whether certain factors better explain agreement strength in each type of conflict.
Bayesian IRT measurement models have been used to study many phenomena in international relations, and the full probability model approach we employ allows these approaches to be used even when data are scarce. We measure the strength of only \Sexpr{nrow(PA_avg)} peace agreements due to limited data availability. Yet due to the additional information contained in the predictors of agreement strength included in the full probability model, we are able to obtain stable estimates of agreement strength despite the small sample size. When lots of data are available, the additional effort required of the full probability model may not be warranted, but when observations are few, the increases in measurement validity make it worthwhile.
It is also important to highlight the shortcomings of our approach. The use of a full probability model that includes predictors in addition to a measurement model allows us to produce stable estimates of agreement strength despite our small sample size. However, this means that our measurements cannot easily be included in other analyses as response or explanatory variables. Instead, researchers must estimate a full probability model using their predictors of interest. The model can be computationally costly, but when data are scare, as with our sample of \Sexpr{nrow(PA)} agreements, we believe that the ability to reliably estimate latent constructs outweighs the added computational burden.
Based on our results here, we make some basic methodological recommendations for researchers wishing to use item response theory to measure the strength of peace agreements. First, if there are any agreements that are especially relevant to your theoretical argument, do not select them as identification restrictions. Agreements used to anchor the latent scale can shift greatly in the ranking of agreements when compared to a model where they are not selected as an identification restriction. However, agreements that are not chosen as identification restrictions rarely move more than five places in the ranking under different identification strategies. Second, use a full probability model instead of separate IRT and regression models. While this strategy is more computationally intensive, the estimates incorporate more information about the phenomena at hand which should lead to better predictive accuracy when used in other analyses.
If future work confirms our findings that mediation can weaken agreements in some contexts, this would suggest that merely solving the time inconsistency problem \cite{Beardsley2008} does not lead to stronger mediated agreements. By being able to measure the strength of peace agreements irrespective of their eventual success or failure, we can increase the range of questions we can ask, leading to a better understanding of conflict termination overall. Bayesian IRT can be used to better measure existing concepts when observations and observable indicators are few, but this paper shows that it can also be used to ask questions we otherwise would not be able to.
% % new page for references
\newpage
\singlespacing
% % bibliography
%TC:incbib
\bibliographystyle{apsr}
\bibliography{Measurement}
\end{document}